NCSG-DISCUSS Archives

NCSG-Discuss

NCSG-DISCUSS@LISTSERV.SYR.EDU

Options: Use Forum View

Use Monospaced Font
Show Text Part by Default
Show All Mail Headers

Message: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Topic: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]
Author: [<< First] [< Prev] [Next >] [Last >>]

Print Reply
Subject:
From:
Harold Feld <[log in to unmask]>
Reply To:
Harold Feld <[log in to unmask]>
Date:
Wed, 6 Dec 2006 09:46:45 -0500
Content-Type:
text/plain
Parts/Attachments:
text/plain (121 lines)
At 06:06 PM 12/5/2006, Milton Mueller wrote:
> >>> Mawaki Chango <[log in to unmask]> 12/5/2006 3:20 PM >>>
> >TERM OF REFERENCE 3
> >Policy for price controls for registry services
> >Policy Recommendation N (Option 2):
> >
> >The NCUC has argued that it is premature to formulate policy in the
> >area of pricing without having had the benefit of an intensely
> >focused study on this topic. They believe that a new PDP is required
> >to address the specific issue of price controls. ("We believe that
> >existing price caps should be left in place for the short term, and
> >another, separate PDP inaugurated on methods and criteria for
> >changing, raising or eliminating price caps in the future.")
> >
> >Thus, another option is to keep the status by encouraging ICANN to
> >continue with existing pricing provisions and initiating a targeted
> >PDP on this issue alone taking into account the upcoming economist's
> >report (http://www.icann.org/minutes/resolutions-18oct06.htm).
> >
> >NCUC: N
>
>Yeah! Good stuff. Also, the "market dominance" analysis in the Option 1
>is fallacious from an economic point of view. To an individual
>registrant with an established domain, opportunistic pricing hurts them
>whether or not the registry is dominant in the total  market.

Allow me to expand on this a bit, because it is important.

The theory of competitive markets holds that competition between 
providers serves consumers (some would say better than 
regulation).  When consumers can freely choose closely substitutable 
products from a variety of vendors, the vendors must work hard to 
attract customers.  Thus, in competitive markets where consumers can 
freely switch, vendors will generally seek to hold prices to the 
lowest profitable level (lest a competitor attract price sensitive 
customers) or offer services that justify a provider premium (e.g., 
better customer service).

There is a difference between whether competitive alternatives are 
available and whether consumers have the ability to take advantage of 
the competitive alternatives.  In economic terms, it is possible that 
the cost of switching from one alternative to another ("switching 
cost") is so high that a consumer cannot switch to a theoretically 
available alternative.  This is called "consumer lock-in."  Lock in 
may also occur if a theoretical alternative is not, in fact available 
to the specific consumer, if the theoretical alternative is not a 
close substitute, or for other reasons.

Finally, where there are relatively few choices, and providers of the 
choices all operate under the same general conditions and with 
considerable knowledge of each other's practices, parallel behavior 
with regard to pricing is likely to occur even in markets that are 
considered "competitive" under most indicia (e.g., have four or more 
equal size firms).

Apply this to the TLD market. There are now five truly generic TLDs 
(.com, .org, .net, .biz, .info), a number of "sponsored" TLDs (e.g., 
.travel) and a number of ccTLDs open to large numbers of registrants 
(but not necessarily all registrants) (e.g., .us (must have U.S. nexus)).

.com and .net are run by the same registry, and are thus unlikely to 
genuinely compete against one another.  Verisign has no incentive to 
try to drive customers from one TLD to the other.  This leaves only 
three competing registries that can be regarded as possibly close substitutes.

But a consumer switching from one TLD to another faces very 
significant costs.  Leaving aside the costs of changing addresses and 
informing everyone else to change the address, a name holder has 
usually invested considerable goodwill in a name.  Even switching 
from Example.TLD1 to Example.TLD2 is likely to create customer 
confusion and dissipate good will by creating inconvenience for 
customers/website visitors.

This gets worse if "Example" is not available in TLD2, since it 
requires not merely a change in TLD, but a substantive change in the 
name.   Finally, the holder of Example.TLD1 that abandons that name 
due to concerns about pricing runs the risk that someone else will 
register Example.TLD1 and exploit the goodwill created by the 
original registrant or create confusion (either innocently or deliberately).

There is also the question of whether the registrant regards TLD1 and 
TLD2 as "substitutes" or "close substitutes."  The difference is 
important.  I regard something as "close substitutes" if I am 
indifferent or care only a little about which one I use.  By 
contrast, if I will use a different product when I must but really 
don't regard it as the same, it is merely a "substitute."  For 
example, Diet Coke and Diet Pepsi are both diet colas.  Many people 
are equally happy drinking Diet Coke or Diet Pepsi, and therefore 
regard them as close substitutes.  I have a strong preference for 
Diet Coke, and regard Diet Pepsi as merely a substitute to use when 
no Diet Coke is available.  Further, while water is also a drink with 
no calories, it is clearly different from a diet cola.  Again, some 
people may regard water as a close substitute, while others merely 
regard it a substitute and will pay a premium for diet cola if that 
is what they genuinely want.

For all these reasons, a name holder may not regard an available 
competitive alternative as actually available, or may endure onerous 
terms the name holder would have rejected when initially selecting a 
TLD in which to register.

Worse from a consumer perspective, the relatively small number of 
providers makes it less likely that the consumer will have a real 
choice.  Even if there is no market power in the usual sense, the 
limited number of competitors ensures that all competitors will 
quickly switch to the more profitable pricing strategy unless there 
is an immediate, strong consumer rejection of the change in pricing 
policy that drives so much business to the few competitors that it is 
worth maintaining the old policy.  But lock in factors discussed 
above make such a mass exodus/market correction unlikely.

In short, "market power" or the presence of possible competitive 
alternatives is not the only measure of whether consumers have 
sufficient real choices to rely on market forces in place of 
regulation.  A better public interest analysis will look not merely 
to the number of possible competitors or even only to market chare, 
but to the nature of consumer lock-in and other factors that may 
limit the ability of competitive market forces to protect consumer interests.

Harold 

ATOM RSS1 RSS2